Comment: Payday loans don’t need more rules; just a new lender

Burdensome rules limit availability to low-income borrowers, but what if the Fed was the lender?

By Stephen L. Carter / Bloomberg Opinion

I’m of two minds about news reports that the Consumer Financial Protection Board is considering strict limitations on payday lending. On the one hand, the practice of loaning money for a short term at high interest is odious; on the other, the libertarian who slumbers uneasily within me worries about paternalism.

The payday industry lends around $90 billion a year, mainly in small-dollar amounts, typically to borrowers with poor credit who can’t get bank loans or credit cards. In general, no collateral is demanded. Instead, the borrower pledges a part of future income. The loans are short term, and, when the borrower can’t pay, are generally rolled over, a practice that can lead to compound interest amounting to several hundred percent.

Hardly anybody thinks payday loans are a good idea; on the other hand, they also offer cash to borrowers who otherwise might not be able to get any, even in an emergency. Too much regulation might price those borrowers out of the loan market completely.

A pair of intriguing new papers shed useful light on the dilemma. One delivers a wealth of information on the effect of regulating payday loans; the second offers a solution so unexpected and innovative that it just might work.

The first paper, by the economists Jialan Wang and Kathleen Burke, looks at the experience of Texas, which in 2011 and 2012 adopted a number of rules governing the issuance of payday loans. The results are striking.

A key requirement of the Texas regulations was that potential borrowers be made aware, in simple terms, of the overall cost of the payday loan compared to overall cost of other forms of credit. Using data collected by the Consumer Financial Protection Board, Wang and Burke calculate that the regulatory change led to a 13 percent decrease in total payday loan dollar volume in the state, as well as an 11 percent decrease in the number of payday loans extended, compared to other states that adopted no new rules. The loans themselves aren’t smaller, but fewer people are using them.

But to opponents of payday loans, the size of the loan matters too. Thus, although Texas’s statewide regulations dealt mostly with disclosure, the cities of Dallas and Austin went further by adopting what amount to underwriting rules. Both cities passed ordinances limiting payday loans to 20 percent of the borrower’s gross monthly income. The rules also restrict the ability of the borrower to roll the loan over without repaying at least 25 percent of the principal.

Rules this draconian would be expected to put a far more serious dent in payday loans. Dallas data are incomplete, but Wang and Burke find that once Austin began enforcing the new rules, the number of loans fell by 41 percent and the total dollar value by an astonishing 62 percent.

This is where I begin to worry. If we reduce the number of payday loans, we make it harder for the poor-in-credit to borrow. As I’ve noted before, they might go to the underground market, or to family and friends, who have no way of pricing or spreading the risk.

True, we might believe that the poor-in-credit are better off not borrowing at all, particularly if they’re funding present consumption (that is, living beyond their means). But paternalism, even with the best of intentions, remains an offense against dignity. On the other hand, payday lending does indeed involve all the abuses that have people worried. The question we should be asking, then, is whether there’s a way to regulate the market for short-term loans to those who can’t get cash elsewhere without unreasonably restricting the ability of the poor-in-credit to borrow.

Which brings us to the second paper, this one by my Yale Law School colleague Jonathan Macey. Like other critics, Macey favors more regulation of payday lenders. But unlike most who clamor for a crackdown, he also recognizes that people with bad credit often face a genuine cash crunch. His innovative solution is that the Federal Reserve — yes, you heard that right — the Fed should make its emergency lending facilities available to low- and moderate-income households forced to borrow in short-term markets for medical care and other essentials.

At first blush this might sound like a stretch. But it isn’t. For one thing, as Macey notes, we use the Fed for plenty of things these days besides stabilizing the banking system. During the pandemic, for example, the Fed has loaned to small and medium-sized businesses, along with large employers. Moreover, as Macey reminds us, there’s reason to believe that as originally conceived, the Fed’s lending facilities were to be available to individuals in exceptional cases. It’s true that the plan was to lend only to collateralized borrowers, but Macey suggests that the Fed solve that problem the same way payday lenders do: by treating the borrower’s future income as collateral.

Macey’s proposal is attractive. He’d limit the loans to emergencies, such as child care or repairs to a motor vehicle; the sorts of things that bring many a potential borrower to the payday lender. The obvious risk is that over time, political pressure might expand the definition of emergency. But unless we take the paternalistic view that the poor-in-credit shouldn’t be able to borrow at all, maybe we should consider that risk more a feature than a bug.

Stephen L. Carter is a professor of law at Yale University and was a clerk to U.S. Supreme Court Justice Thurgood Marshall. His latest nonfiction book is “Invisible: The Forgotten Story of the Black Woman Lawyer Who Took Down America’s Most Powerful Mobster.”

Talk to us

> Give us your news tips.

> Send us a letter to the editor.

> More Herald contact information.

More in Opinion

toon
Editorial cartoons for Friday, June 20

A sketchy look at the news of the day.… Continue reading

Glacier Peak, elevation 10,541 feet, in the Glacier Peak Wilderness of Mount Baker–Snoqualmie National Forest in Snohomish County, Washington. (Caleb Hutton / The Herald) 2019
Editorial: Sell-off of public lands a ruinous budget solution

The proposal in the Senate won’t aid affordable housing and would limit recreational opportunities.

Schwab: At least those in the parade were having a good time

Denied a menacing ‘tone’ from parading soldiers, Trump’s countenance betrayed an unhappy birthday.

Saunders: What Trump is seeking is an Iran with no nukes

There are risks if the U.S. joins in Israel’s war with Iran, but the risks are greater if it doesn’t.

Comment: Ruling on gender-affirming care flawed, cruel

It deferring to state legislatures, the majority ignores precedent on serving the rights of minority groups.

Kristof: Global hunger is easy to solve; actually, we had

Solutions for parasites and malnutrition are at hand. It’s the will to fund programs that is now missing.

Comment: GOP retreat from gay marriage a threat to court ruling

Conservatives have already begun work, as they did with abortion, to overturn the gay marriage ruling.

Comment: Juneteenth holiday struggles to build on promise

The young federal holiday — and the racial equity it seeks — face unfamiliarity and anti-DEI efforts.

What’s state’s role in county funding for stadium

Is the state of Washington jamming money down the county’s throat to… Continue reading

Comment: RFK Jr.’s remake of vaccine panel puts nation at risk

Clearing out the committee and appointing those critical of vaccines will result in more outbreaks.

Comment: Immigration debacle shows failure as nation of laws

No fix will be possible until both parties stop using the crisis for their own political purposes.

Support local journalism

If you value local news, make a gift now to support the trusted journalism you get in The Daily Herald. Donations processed in this system are not tax deductible.